Evaluate the function and aims of stabilisation clauses and comment on how they seek to achieve the stability that parties’ desire.
The foreign investor who tends to participate in the international petroleum industry is typically a long term investor due to capital intensive nature of the underlying industry. Such ventures are vulnerable on account of any unilateral action by the host government which may adversely impact the interests of the foreign investor (Berger, 2003). A potential remedy for the above concern is in the form of a stabilisation clause which acts as a guarantee against unilateral action on the part of the host nation. These clauses are common in the modern day petroleum contracts especially if the host country is politically unstable. The origin of the stabilisation clause as part of the petroleum contracts can be traced back to the 1930’s when the interests of the American oil companies were jeopardised due to the mass nationalisation of strategic assets initiated by Latin American countries. Till the 1970’s, the stabilisation clause offered protection against expropriation. During the 1970’s, there were several arbitral awards for nationalisation of assets which gave rise to better understanding of mutual interests on the part of host government from 1980’s (Cameron, 2006). It was hoped that this would eliminate the need for the stabilisation clause but this has not been the case. Instead, the mechanisms to implement these clauses have got more complex and varied in nature depending upon the credibility of the host nation (Fortier & Stephen, 2004).
Since the turn of the 21st century, there have been numerous attempts on the part of the host governments of petroleum producing nations to alter the fiscal arrangements present in the petroleum contracts. Although the underlying motive behind these attempts was not uniform, but one factor that paid a crucial role was the surge in international crude prices (Berger, 2003). This led to a fundamental shift in the bargaining power in the hands of the oil producing nations as a result of which, these nations wanted to benefit from this surge in oil prices. This phenomenon is not just limited to the third world countries but also includes the OECD producers such as UK and USA. A case in point is that of UK which in December 2005, increased the taxation burden with regards to petroleum by 100% as it was indicated that returns in the North Sea had reached a level of 40% from the normal levels of 13%. This increase in returns led the government to introduce changes which enhanced their share of the oil frenzy. Similar case was also observed in case of USA with regards to the oil being produced from the Gulf of Mexico (Cameron, 2006). However, it would be naïve to believe that this was the major or only factor that led to unilateral actions on the part of the host government.
In case of certain third world countries which had oil resources, stabilisation clauses were offered in the 1990’s so as to attract investment and mitigate the underlying political risk. However, in a bid to offer exceptionally robust deals to investors, the financial implications of these are often not understood by the host government at the time of extension. This is particularly true for these nations which had limited exposure with regards to implementation of these clauses. However, when later these clauses are put into practice, they are found to be highly inflexible and lead to dispute which leads to alteration of the fiscal arrangements. An example of this phenomenon is experiences in Kazakhstan (Comeaux & Kinsella,1994). However, a positive aspect of such alterations is that these are primarily forced and once altered, these are usually backed by subsequent stabilisation clauses which offer protection against future unilateral action. Certain governments alter their tax regimes which tend to have a direct or indirect impact on the fiscal obligations for the foreign investor. In case of absence of stabilisation clause, there are procedures for negotiation and redressed so that the disturbed equilibrium can be again restored. With contracts having the stabilisation clause, arbitration acts as key provision which discourages the government from taking unilateral actions (Coaele, 2002).
From the above discussion, it is evident that in wake of the empirical incidents involving unilateral actions which are not limited to any particular geography, stabilisation clauses have become a mandatory component of such agreements leading to the proliferation of the same. In order to implement stabilisation clauses in the petroleum contracts, it is imperative to understand that the most crucial aspect of any such contract is the fiscal regime that essentially drives the division of profits between the host governments or state owned oil company and the foreign investor (Bouchez, 1991). This is essentially wider in scope than just tax and royalties and would also involve clauses related to recovery of cost along with profit sharing ratio. Besides there are other aspects that are critical which involve security of titles, right to sell or export petroleum, repatriation norms with regards to foreign currency along with flexibility on operational norms. Thus, stabilisation is required beyond the fiscal regime only as other aspects may have significant impact on the underlying profits generated (Dolzer, 2002).
There are various enforcement mechanisms with regards to achieving stabilisation of both fiscal and non-fiscal regime. One of the most primitive ones in this regard is freezing of the contractual agreement clauses to any unilateral action on the part of the state. A blanket freezing encompassing both the fiscal and non-fiscal clauses of the contract is rather uncommon, however milder forms of freezing are often observed particularly those limiting themselves to the fiscal clauses only. Freezing was common in the era of nationalisation by the government but in the modern day, it inevitably leads to inflexibility and hence is implemented in the form of partial stability provided to the foreign contractor with regards to the key clauses (Cameron, 2006).
Another measure to ensure stabilisation is economic balancing. The economic balancing provisions advocate rebalancing if changes in the contract are executed after the conclusion of the agreement and these changes are detrimental to the interest of either of the parties or both the parties involved in the contract. Economic balancing may be achieved in namely two forms one is automatic and the other is through negotiated amendments in the contract with the intention of rebalancing. In case of automatic rebalancing, the stipulated action is clearly stated in the contract for various unilateral actions and is implemented automatically once triggered. However, considering the wide range of unilateral actions possible for the state, usually economic rebalancing is achieved through negotiated amendments (Hansen, 1988).
Further, in the event that negotiated amendments cannot be concluded, then the right to arbitration is also included as part of the economic balancing stabilisation clause. Besides, normally a mix of the automatic and negotiated approach is usually adopted so as to resolve the common issues faced through automatic rebalancing while the uncommon issues can be resolved through negotiated approach (Salacuse, 2001). It is imperative to note that it is not always that unilateral action by the host government would be harmful to the interests of the foreign investor and may fact at times be beneficial. Further, it may so happen that at times that state government may not unilaterally take an action but due to alteration of laws in the neighbouring country, the prevalent law may change which may adversely impact the investor’s interest. The stabilisation clauses do not tend to cover such action which was evident in the case of Kazakhstan where the VAT rate charge was linked to the corresponding charge in Russia and therefore when Russia hiked its tax, Kazakhstan had no choice but to increase its tax even though it did not had any direct intent to do the same (Cameron, 2006).Therefore, despite the best of intent by both parties, there are limitations to the economic balances stabilisation.
Yet another mode of achieving stabilisation is the intangible cause which ensures that no modification in the petroleum contracts would be initiated on a unilateral basis by any of the parties and any modifications what so ever would be enacted only with the mutual consent of the various contracting parties. It is imperative to note that such clauses unlike unfreezing do not provide immunity against the legislative action but merely provide protection against any unilateral action. This is often found in the modern day petroleum contracts when absolute immunity is a rarity and in order to safeguard mutual interests of the parties, such clauses are inserted into the agreements (Dolzer, 2002). Further, another means of providing stability to the foreign investor practised in certain nations is through legislative support. In this, the concluded agreements are ratified by the parliament of the host country so as to accord legal status to such agreements. Usually this provides much security to the foreign investor although this in effect would be notional as alike other statutory laws, this may also be altered by the parliament at the future date and hence may defeat the purpose but yet in certain third world countries, it was a highly popular measure amongst investors as it provided some semblance to them (Amador,1993).
Further, there are certain stabilisation mechanisms which are found in international law and seek to protect the aim of the investor against any arbitrary action of the state. One of the most common measure in this regard is the BIT (Bilateral Investment Treaty). This treaty is enacted typically between two nations with the intention of providing protection to the interests of foreign investors (hailing from the two respective countries) against reckless and arbitrary state action. One of the prevalent mechanisms present in BIT is the ISDS (Investor State Dispute Settlement) system which typically calls for international arbitration so as to ensure that the interest of the foreign investor is safeguarded (Bouchez, 1991). In case of petroleum contracts, it is not assumed that international law is automatically applicable but still in the presence of BIT and considering the stakes, diplomatic pressure and international arbitration cannot be denied. But it is advisable, that during negotiation of the contract, the foreign investor should press for the inclusion of this principle irrespective of the presence of BIT or not. This is especially imperative as the legal system in third world nations is found wanting and can be tardy, corrupt and state controlled (Cameron, 2006).
It is imperative to note that the stabilisation clauses are offered by certain nations only where the perceived political risk is high coupled with geological risk. Countries such as OSCD where the political regime is highly stable and based on rule of law, the stabilisation clauses are not offered. Further, countries such as Saudi Arabia and Brazil with proven oil reserves also do not offer stabilisation clauses. However, other nations do use this as an incentive to attract foreign investors (Berger, 2003). While stabilisation through various above mechanisms may lure investors, however there are certain limitations which may limit its scope. Firstly, the stabilisation clauses must be in line with the legal framework of the host country. This is particularly true with regards to freezing clauses which do not stand the test of the time as the laws that would be enacted in the future would prevail over the freezing clause as the sovereignty of the host nation is paramount (Chatterjee, 1988). Secondly, stabilisation clauses tend to be restrictive in scope and therefore focus on mainly the fiscal regime while ignoring the non-fiscal clauses which are increasingly gaining more importance (Cameron, 2006).
From the above discussion, it may be concluded that foreign investors aim to achieve stabilisation in petroleum contracts especially when operations are based in countries having high political risk and/or geological risk. However, over the period of time the mechanism of providing stabilisation has altered from freezing to other measures that have been discussed. Typically, a mix of the various measures is deployed in the contracts to provide stability to the investors. The relevance of these clauses continue to remain, however their ambit should expand and seek to include the non-fiscal regime as environment increases is becoming a significant parameter (Cameron, 2006). Further, the host governments on their part should also understand the risks of taking unilateral actions and should aim for actions based on mutual consent and respect for the interests of the various parties involved.
References
Amador, G 1993, “State Responsibility in Case of “Stabilisation” Clauses”, Journal of Transnational Law and Policy, Vol.2 No. 2, pp. 23-50
Berger, P 2003, “Renegotiation and Adaptation of International Investment Contracts: The Role of Contract Drafters and Arbitrators”, Vanderbilt Journal of Transnational Law, Vol. 36 No. 2, pp. 1347- 1380.
Bouchez, LJ 1991, “The Prospects for International Arbitration: Disputes Between States and Private Enterprises”, Journal of International Arbitration, Vol.8 No. 3, pp. 81-115.
Cameron PD 2006, Stabilisation in Investment Contracts and Changes of Rules in Host Countries: Tools for Oil & Gas Investors, AIPN, Available online from https://www.rmmlf.org/Istanbul/4-Stabilisation-Paper.pdf (Accessed on July 25, 2016)
Chatterjee, SK 1988, “The Stabilisation Clause Myth in Investment Agreements”, Journal of International Arbitration, Vol.5 No. 4, pp. 97-111.
Coaele, MTB 2002, “Stabilisation Clauses in International Petroleum Transactions”, Denver Journal of International Law and Policy, Vol.30 No. 3, pp. 217-237.
Comeaux, PE & Kinsella, SN 1994, “Reducing Political Risk in Developing Countries: Bilateral Investment Treaties, Stabilisation Clauses and MIGA & OPIC Investment Insurance”, New York Law School Journal of International & Comparative Law, Vol.15 No. 4, pp. 1- 48.
Dolzer, R 2002, “Indirect Expropriations: New Developments?” New York University Environmental Law Journal, Vol. 11 No.4, pp. 64-93.
Fortier, LY & Stephen LD 2004, ‘Indirect Expropriation in the Law of International Investment: I Know it When I See It’, ICSID Review – Foreign Investment Law Journal, Vol. 19 No. 5, pp. 293-296
Hansen, TB 1988, “The Legal Effect of Given Stabilisation Clauses in Economic Development Agreements”, Virginia Journal of International Law, Vol.28 No. 3, pp. 1015-1041.
Salacuse, JW 2001, “Renegotiating International Business Transactions: The Continuing Struggle of Life Against Form”, International Lawyer, Vol.35 No. 5, pp.1507-1541.
Essay Writing Service Features
Our Experience
No matter how complex your assignment is, we can find the right professional for your specific task. Contact Essay is an essay writing company that hires only the smartest minds to help you with your projects. Our expertise allows us to provide students with high-quality academic writing, editing & proofreading services.Free Features
Free revision policy
$10Free bibliography & reference
$8Free title page
$8Free formatting
$8How Our Essay Writing Service Works
First, you will need to complete an order form. It's not difficult but, in case there is anything you find not to be clear, you may always call us so that we can guide you through it. On the order form, you will need to include some basic information concerning your order: subject, topic, number of pages, etc. We also encourage our clients to upload any relevant information or sources that will help.
Complete the order formOnce we have all the information and instructions that we need, we select the most suitable writer for your assignment. While everything seems to be clear, the writer, who has complete knowledge of the subject, may need clarification from you. It is at that point that you would receive a call or email from us.
Writer’s assignmentAs soon as the writer has finished, it will be delivered both to the website and to your email address so that you will not miss it. If your deadline is close at hand, we will place a call to you to make sure that you receive the paper on time.
Completing the order and download